Farm to Factory: A Reinterpretation of the Soviet Industrial Revolution (The Princeton Economic History of the Western World)
M**L
Excellent orthodox defense of Soviet industrialization policy
Robert Allen has done what few people have attempted - defending Soviet, in particular Stalinist, industrialization policy from the viewpoint and with the methodology of orthodox neoclassical economics. In so doing he reacts particularly against the works of Paul Gregory, the main academic defender of the thesis that the Czarist system would have developed Russia faster and better than the USSR did. Allen takes great pains to refute this position.Allen shows that the Stalinist policy of industrialization followed the strategy laid out by Preobrazhensky, namely to use terms of trade between agriculture and industry to use the agricultural surplus for investment in heavy industry. All the heavy industry production would then be reinvested in that heavy industry, leading over time to a very fast and strong development of industrialization in the USSR. Although this meant in the short term that living standards, as measured by consumption of consumer goods, would increase but little (and even drop during certain periods), in the long run the result would be that the industrial capacity so built up could be used for production of consumer goods eventually at a much higher level than would otherwise have been the case.This has always been much contested by most economists, both socialist and anti-socialist, especially since the system of NEP seemed to perform decently well and created much more stability than the Stalinist heavy industry planning did. Nonetheless, Allen shows through modelling the different factors involved in simulations of alternative paths that the Preobrazhensky strategy was entirely correct, and indeed had the required results. In fact, Allen argues contrary to most historians of the Soviet 1930s that living standards generally did not even drop during this period, with the exception of the years of collectivization of agriculture.This collectivization is also a subject he addresses, where he, again against almost everyone else, finds that it had a slight positive effect, because it made the marketing (in the sense of bringing into circulation) of agricultural produce much larger proportionally and much easier. This solved the recurring problem in the early USSR of ensuring the peasantry sold sufficient of their produce to feed the large urban population, despite the living standards of the Soviet peasants being low. As Allen shows, there was also a great excess of manpower in Soviet agriculture, so the mechanization that accompanied collectivization allowed millions of redundant peasants to move to the cities. It is this generation of peasants-turned-cadres that would form the main basis of support for Stalin and his policies, as is confirmed by Fitzpatrick and others. Of course, given the enormous human cost of collectivization and the famine that followed it, it is still dubious whether the undertaking was overall worth it. In his simulations Allen also traces alternatives such as industrialization without collectivization, which performs slightly worse, a continuation of NEP, which performs significantly worse but still well, and a 'capitalist path' where unemployment was possible and every individual company had to be profit-making; as one could expect, this path works by far the worst. In fact, because the wheat and railroad booms that buoyed the Czarist government in the period 1905-1914 would have ended in the 1920s, a continuation of this road would have brought Russia no further than the level now shown by Mexico or Argentina.The final part of this book contains a much smaller and less detailed discussion of the failures of the Soviet planning models in the late 1970s and the 1980s. The author here makes various subtle and interesting arguments. Firstly, he points out that investment put into military production and upkeep was from a purely economic point of view practically entirely wasted, mostly because it came at the expense of investment in other types of heavy industry than armaments, which the USSR dearly needed. The enormous losses of WWII also contributed here, with much capital being destroyed. A second result here was the enormous costs in manpower for the USSR of their almost Pyrrhic victory in WWII - the end of large quantities of newly free labor coming in from the countryside limited the expansion possibilities of all labor-intensive industry, which the USSR had hitherto relied on. Here again appears as useful the model of Soviet economics developed by Abram Feldman, which explored the interaction between capital and labor and how extra capital in a poor country like the 1920s USSR could lead to a positive feedback loop effect if invested in heavy industry (i.e. production of more 'capital'), since every unit of capital in such a situation led to vastly larger increases in output than every new unit of labor. From the late 1960s on labor, however, became the main constraint in output, and the old Preobrazhensky accumulation strategy no longer worked.The main question is of course why the Soviet government did not adequately respond to this, and here Allen is for the first time severely critical: he identifies a number of major planning and investment errors on the part of the Brezhnev leadership. The most important of these is the wasteful retooling and upkeep of old industry where the production of new modern industry would have been more efficient, and secondly extremely wasteful unproductive investment in raw materials production in Siberia. This latter part was the result of the minerals and oil production in European Russia, the Ukraine etc. being largely depleted, so expansion had to be sought in Siberia, where costs were vastly higher. Coal production in the Donbass region peaked in 1976, after which the Soviet government was forced to massively invest in lignite (brown coal) production in Krasnoiarsk. Brown coal is not very efficient and the costs of operating in a vast desolate area as central Siberia are high, so that productivity of capital invested plummeted. Much the same applied to oil. Only natural gas production was something of a success story, which can still be seen today in Russia's position as major exporter of natural gas to the European continent.Allen negatively compares this autarkic development strategy to that pursued by Japan, which had much fewer natural resources after WWII, but nonetheless greatly expanded its industrial production in these sectors by importing the raw materials. Drops in transport costs after the war made this profitably possible. Of course, the USSR, as Allen acknowledges, had political reasons for indigenous development even at higher costs, where Japan could operate entirely as an American vassal. It must be said though that Soviet energy use was very high per $1000 of GDP, and that conservation programs and saving the natural environment mostly failed due to the antique state of much of Soviet industry and the enormous scale of its factories. Short term "shock" responses to these problems by Brezhnev and successive governments only made the situation worse. Here Allen points to systematic deficiencies in proper cost accounting and saving, which had (correctly) not been a priority in the 1930s, but had to become one in the 1970s. The Soviet political system at that time was not very well-suited to adapt to this, and Brezhnev et al.'s 'dropping the ball' on these major economic reform issues played a large part in the fall of this system. Allen emphasizes though that it was not planning as such that failed, just that the plans were bad. These analyses are also along the lines of those provided in Paresh Chattopadhyay's excellent study of Soviet economic policy.Overall this book is an excellent and highly stimulating discussion of Soviet industrialization programs and their beneficial effects as well as their failures. It is decidedly non-political and does not enter into any ideological question, but despite its thorough orthodoxy in methods, it is nonetheless very sensible - indeed Allen shows that such methods CAN be used in an intelligent manner when one really wants to. It must also be mentioned that poor Preobrazhensky had little benefit from the success of his strategy: he was shot in 1937.
A**J
Books like this are more important now than ever before
Informative, well written
L**A
The USSR: Success, failure, or somewhere in between?
Generally speaking the USSR's economy is dismissed as a failure for a variety of reasons. This book does what few have dared to due in the post Soviet world, argue that it was a success. I think its important to note that Allen is not a hardcore Marxist who believes that "Stalin did nothing wrong" or "Holdomor was a big lie", he is a mainstream economist using mainstream methodology to assess the Soviet economy.In terms of its quality as a book, Farm to Factory is top notch, but not simple. 10 chapters and an appendix jam-packed with detailed statistics, computer simulations, and and constant comparison and discussion of the validity of the relevant facts. Its both interesting a piece of economic history as well as provocative defense of Soviet planning. The book isn't easy though, and isn't really intended for general audiences. As a prerequisite some understanding of intermediate macroeconomics would help a reader work through the mathematical aspects that dominate much of the book. Robert Allen includes his equations and computer simulations which both shows his own confidence in his work as well as the fact that the book really insn't meant for a layperson.Allen argues that its misleading to simply compare the USSR with America and the West. Nations that were rich in 2000 were generally rich in 1900, and in going back to 1800, still rich. Russia was poor in 1820 and 1900. It had grown pretty substantially by 1989, only Japan had grown faster and no countries in Latin America, the Middle East, Africa, or South Asia could compare. Investment in industry lead to increased consumption, especially after the disastrous famine in the early 30's. Calorie intake went up, life expectancies increased, education became universal while many Asian nations like India and Indonesia remained rural with far more serious issues in terms of nutrition and literacy. The consumer revolution in the USSR wasn't very impressive compared to W. Europe or N. America in terms of quality or quantity, but consumer durables were far more common and better there than in Iraq, Turkey, or Argentina. Only a few East Asian countries, usually with their own version of government planning, had joined the rich countries starting in the mid to late 80's. Sudden and massive urbanization lead to a fertility decline. Allen had demographic model that shows without the education of women and the promotion of their rights the USSR may have had a population of almost 1 billion by 1989. Poverty tends to result in very high fertility regimes and everywhere in the USSR, even predominantly Muslim parts like the less developed Central Asian republics saw a decline in birth rates. Under the leadership of the communist party the USSR perform well by global standards, even including the slowdown after 70/75.Other issues dealt with include development before 1917, the New Economic Policy, planning, collectivization(Allen's boldest claim is that it nudged up growth), and finally the growth slowdown. Like a lot of books on the Soviet economy the books weakness is that there is very little on the post Stalin years. In fairness they aren't as interesting due to the drama, human tragedy, and epic push towards industrialization that occurred in the 20's and 30's. As the book goes forward in history there is less and less information as people just haven't studied them nearly as much as the Stalin and Lenin years. Most of the book deals wit the USSR before the 50's. During that time in the 60's and 70's planners, party leaders, and bureaucrats doubled down on Stalin's previous policies. According to Allen the issue was a "lack of imagination at the top". An accumulation of bad ideas was clogging the Soviet engine of growth. The people entrusted with being in charge of planning decisions refused to change until it was too late. One thing I would point out is that book doesn't discuss why the USSR collapsed, merely what happened to its economy. In my opinion why the USSR as a legal entity collapsed is a much more political question than economic. After all, many nations suffer economic decline but they persist as a country.In my own opinion the USSR was mostly a success. Like Allen, my endorsement is hardly unqualified. Stalin and other party leaders were needlessly brutal, their paranoia and obsession with industrialization killed, tortured, imprisoned, exiled and starved millions. The communists inherited an autocratic and famine prone society. In the medium run they grew the economy, improved people's quality of life, and developed technology that took them into space. But, in the long run it all came crashing down. Had Gorbachov pulled of some successful reform program like in China(perhaps reverting to an NEP-style economy with private agriculture and small enterprises) they might have lasted into the 21st century. But, alas, that is the markets greatest strength, no one person or group of people( communist party officials, planners, administrators, generals, bureaucrats) is really in charge and can really be blamed if things go wrong. It was only a matter of time until bad plans were drafted and when they were the people rose up, unless Gorbachev was willing to declare marital law, and he wasn't, the USSR was eventually going to face this economic quandary of bad plans.I recommend this book be read along side the followingFaulty Foundations: Soviet Economic Policies, 1928-1940An Economic History of the USSR 1917-1991 (4th, and final, Edition)The Economic Transformation of the Soviet Union 1913-1945
J**R
War die sowjetische Planwirtschaft vom ökonomischen Standpunkt von Beginn an ein Fehlschlag? Nein...
...ist die Antwort von Allen, demonstriert mit Statistik und Ökonometrie, nicht bis 1970 !! War die Kollektivierung ökonomisch notwendig - abgesehen von den politischen und menschlichen Kosten - Nein, sagt Allen. Da würden ihm allerdings Raupach u.a. widersprechen. Die NEP war keineswegs auf die - mit hohen und unnötigen menschlichen Kosten verbundene - Blitzindustrialisierung ausgerichtet. ...und ohne diese Industrialisierung eines rückständigen Landes wäre die Massenproduktion von Waffen im Ural, Sibirien 1941-1945 unmöglich gewesen, ohne diese Waffen hätte die Wehrmacht, hätte Hitler den Krieg gewonnen, gar kein Zweifel ! Die alliierte Militärhilfe betrug nicht mehr als 10% der sowjetischen Produktion ! Würden das diejenigen befürworten, die die Politik der Dreissiger Jahre in Grund und Boden verdammen ? Jedenfalls ist das Buch eine gute Diskussionsgrundlage.
D**E
Outstandingb economic history
Readable and understandable to the non specialist without dumbing down.
C**7
Un peccato che un libro così non sia ancora stato tradotto.
l modello di industrializzazione sovietico è stato un fallimento o no? Dati alla mano, Robert Allen smonta tutti i luoghi comuni e le imprecisioni legate alla storia economica dell'Unione Sovietica, illustrando il fenomenale processo di "catch-up" avvenuto in particolare tra il 1928 e i 1970. La panoramica fornita da Allen è approfonditissima e dettagliata: dall'economia pre-rivoluzionaria al comunismo di guerra, dalla NEP alla collettivizzazione forzata, passando per i dibattiti sull'industrializzazione tra Fel'dman, Preobrazhensky e Bukharin.Tra i grandi traguardi dell'opera, due sono di massima importanza: il primo è l'aver dimostrato come il processo di pianificazione centrale, l'aumento del tasso di investimento e - in misura minore - la collettivizzazione dell'agricoltura ebbero grandi effetti, in particolare per l'economia urbana, comportando una notevole crescita dei beni di consumo a partire dagli anni Trenta; il secondo è che la brutalità di Stalin ebbe effetti economici scarsissimi, implicando anzi un eccesso di mortalità (dovuto sia alla collettivizzazione che alla rapida transizione demografica) e portando modesti contributi alla crescita economica (come mostrano anche i dati derivanti dalla simulazione di uno scenario di non abbandono della NEP, la cui minor efficacia nello spostare lavoratori dalla campagna alla città è spiegata solo dal terrorismo staliniano). La collettivizzazione forzata, nelle parole di Allen "ritardò la crescita durante il primo piano quinquennale e la accelerò dopo, ma l'effetto cumulativo durante gli anni Trenta fu solo quello di un piccolo incremento dell'espansione economica. La miseria umana che accompagnò la collettivizzazione fu davvero vasta, mentre i guadagni economici magri".
L**A
ottimo
il libro è arrivato in pochi giorni e in ottime condizioni: ha soddisfatto pienamente le aspettative previste. anche il contenuto era esattamente quello descritto
Trustpilot
5 days ago
1 day ago